Fleet News

‘Road pricing should form part of UK transport policy’

A group of academics and transport professionals have reignited the debate on road-user charging by suggesting the network could grind to a halt if drastic action isn’t taken.

Department for Transport figures predict traffic will increase by 19% from 2015 to 2025 and by more than 40% between now and 2040.

The Government is attempting to alleviate the pressure by ploughing £50 billion into the country’s roads – the largest programme of investment for more than half a century.

However, experts suggest a more radical approach is required if gridlock is to be avoided.

Dr John Walker, a lecturer in automotive engineering at the University of Southampton, said: “Road pricing should become an integral part of our road transport policy.”

Walker told delegates at a Transport Select Committee Parliamentary outreach conference, held at the University of Southampton, that: “Technology lets us offer a better deal to road users, with motoring taxes replaced by more effective pay-as-you-drive schemes, but it’s hard to convince politicians and drivers of the benefits.”

Walker referred to a road pricing scheme in Stockholm, which was trialled in 2006. Initially, there was 32% opposition to the scheme, but as the trial progressed people saw the benefits and opposition waned.

A referendum following the trial showed a majority in favour and it was permanently introduced. Support has continued to grow and now stands at 74%.

Walker explained that there is usually a low point in public opinion before a scheme is introduced. “This is exactly the wrong time to hold a referendum,” he said.

That is what happened in Manchester when residents rejected a congestion charging scheme in 2008, when more than £2.7bn worth of public transport funding depended on a ‘yes’ vote.

Public opinion, unsurprisingly, continues to guide political will, with road charging schemes being ditched by both the current Government and previous administration.

Louise Ellman MP, chairman of the Transport Select Committee, said the previous Labour Government was close to implementing road-user charging but a petition, which attracted two million signatures against the scheme, put pay to it.

More recently, a plan to introduce road tolls on the A14 was scrapped after a public outcry, with roads minister Robert Goodwill suggesting tolls were now off the agenda completely.

Professor Mike McDonald, emeritus professor of transportation engineering at the University of Southampton, said it’s a question of trust. “Studies have shown that the problem is people have a lack of trust that the money from road-user charging will be fed back in to the system,” he added.

“However, the amount of money now coming from road taxation is very close to the amount of money the Government is going to have to spend on improving and maintaining the transport infrastructure.

“Is this a unique opportunity to ringfence that money so that you change the basis of taxation to a road-user charging model where money is fed back into transport?”

Sharon Kindleysides, managing director of Kapsch and chairman of Intelligent Transport Systems, said that public perception is stopping politicians from taking a lead.

“The politicians are scared of implementing road user charging because they think people might be against it,” she said. “However, it is the only way to increase capacity; it’s the only way for people to pay fairly for the roads.”

Nevertheless, whatever the virtues are of any particular system, Ellman recognises there is a real problem in convincing the public that road pricing will work.

She explained: “The concept, which was looked at was based on shifting funding from road taxation to the ‘use’ of the roads.

“But that affects different individuals in different ways and I think there was maximum scope for the media to produce headlines that made people think they would have to pay enormous amounts of money to be able to get to work, or do something that is absolutely essential. That might not have been true but people were given that impression.”

Referring to the timing of the referendum in Stockholm, she added: “Perhaps the lesson learned is to take account of the electoral cycle.”  

Leave a comment for your chance to win £20 of John Lewis vouchers.

Every issue of Fleet News the editor picks his favourite comment from the past two weeks – get involved for your chance to appear in print and win!

Login to comment

Comments

  • Peter Roberts - 28/04/2014 14:43

    Professor Mike McDonald is wrong. The main objections to road pricing are the surveillance of every journey required to make it work and also the costs associated with road pricing. Road pricing cannot work without precise details of every journey being recorded and kept in a database which is then used to charge the 'customer'. The second serious objection is the cost of introducing and maintaining the road pricing systems and technology. It is simply naive to think the costs of recording every journey and sending a monthly bill to each road user will be minimal. Most estimates put this at some £7bn a year which is somewhere near the total collected in VED today. Then you have the privatisation of the roads which of course would be easier if pricing was available but; would the government be able to reduce current motoring taxation to entirely compensate road users for the pay-as-you-go journeys? The answer is clearly no, so in truth road pricing adds significant costs to the road user and returns no benefit except to those providing the scheme. Professor Mike McDonald should listen to the public on this and stop trying to promote a system which is unacceptable to pretty much everyone except the odd academic and those who will make serious money at the expense of the travelling public. It is also misleading to suggest the Stockholm scheme was voted through in a referendum. This referendum was restricted to the areas of Stockholm immediately in the charging zone who might see a reduction of traffic and areas outside the charging zone where most commuters and road users lived were excluded from the decision. Even then the scheme passed with the narrowest of margins. It is a pity we are still having this discussion when it is abundantly clear the people who pay for the roads - the travelling public do not want road pricing but do want to see some of the existing tax taken from VED and fuel taxes used to support our road network and not frittered away elsewhere.

  • Chris - 29/04/2014 07:01

    If these professors think road pricing is such a great idea why don't they stand for election for parliament under the "Academic Experts Party" banner? Either that or put a sock in it and do their proper job. Oh wait, they're 'teaching' students about transport policy? Let's hope the students are more intelligent than they are.

  • Dr John Walker - 15/05/2014 18:18

    As one of the people quoted in the original article, I would like to correct one error in it; a survey commissioned by the newspaper Svenska Dagbladet a week before charging began showed 69% opposed to the charge, 23% in favour and 8% unsure – not 32% opposition as the article has it. But in a referendum shortly after the trial, Stockholm citizens voted to reinstate the scheme permanently, with 51.3% in favour and 45.5% against – a small majority, as Peter Roberts says, but a majority nonetheless. It is true that 60.2% of referendum respondents in Stockholm county voted “no” and only 39.8% voted “yes” - but in May 2011, a poll covering most of the county showed support for the charges had increased to over 70%. Also Professor Mike McDonald is correct to say that support for road pricing increases if the revenue is ring-fenced and fed back into transport – see the examples in my report for the RAC Foundation, “The Acceptability of Road Pricing”. http://www.racfoundation.org/research/economics/road-pricing-acceptability. Peter Roberts says that “Road pricing cannot work without precise details of every journey being recorded and kept in a database which is then used to charge the 'customer'”. This is not true, as experience in the United States demonstrates. The Oregon Department of Transportation is setting up a mileage-based charging scheme for 5,000 volunteer motorists beginning July 1, 2015, charging 1.5 cents per mile for up to 5,000 volunteer cars and light commercial vehicles, with a “gas tax” refund to those participants. This is the start of an alternate method of generating fuel tax from specific vehicles to pay for Oregon highways. See http://www.oregon.gov/ODOT/HWY/RUFPP/pages/ruc_overview.aspx , where the enabling legislation can be downloaded and where the background to it is explained. Participants have a choice of charging methods, at least one of which must be non-location-specific (i.e. not GPS). Other options include a flat annual rate offering unlimited miles, a plug-in module that simply records miles driven, and a smart-phone app that distinguishes in-state and out-of-state miles. The scheme also protects driver privacy - personal trip information must be destroyed within 30 days of being used for billing. All proceeds will go into the State Highway Fund and will be spent 50% on state highways, 30% on county roads, and 20% on city streets. The costs associated with road pricing may also be less than Mr Roberts suggests. According to the US-based Reason Foundation (“Dispelling the Myths: Toll and Fuel Tax Collection Costs in the 21st Century” By Daryl S. Fleming): • “The cost of collection for motor fuel tax revenues is significantly greater than the widely believed figure of 1% of the revenue collected. Indirect costs, such as losses incurred at several levels of the process and taxes hidden in the collection of revenues (some are even imposed on those exempt from the fuel tax program), suggest that the costs of motor fuel tax collections may well be in the vicinity of 5% of the revenue collected”. • “Cost data for some All-Electronic Toll operations in the United States demonstrate that the net collection costs of an AET operation can be in the vicinity of 5% of the revenue collected for a $5.00 toll (or 8% of revenue collected for a $2.00 toll)”. Admittedly these are US figures, but with improved technology and the wider adoption of electronic tolling, the costs of collection are continually falling. And of course, road pricing, unlike taxation, has powerful traffic management capabilities. Note also that my suggestion at the above seminar was not that the UK should immediately adopt road pricing, but that it should be brought back onto the transport agenda and properly evaluated. Finally, to quote Sir Rod Eddington’s 2006 report: ‘The potential for benefits from a well-designed, large-scale road pricing scheme is unrivalled by any other intervention’. Dr John Walker Senior Visiting Research Fellow, Transportation Research Group, University of Southampton

Compare costs of your company cars

Looking to acquire new vehicles? Check how much they'll cost to run with our Car Running Cost calculator.

What is your BIK car tax liability?

The Fleet News car tax calculator lets you work out tax costs for both employer and employee